In my last article I had outlined how Russia has now joined the other former Communist countries China and Vietnam in embracing what can be called authoritarian capitalism. The economic prosperity this has brought is now being reflected in large foreign exchange resources accruing to the State, which are increasingly being used to buy shares including outright takeovers - of Western companies. The resulting role of sovereign wealth funds and State-controlled companies in the global economy is now being hotly debated. But the discussion has been vitiated by the reluctance of the participants (notably in the Financial Times) to get to the political heart of the matter by calling a �spade a spade�. This article attempts to fill this lacuna.
Authoritarian capitalism needs to be distinguished from corporatism. It combines varying degrees of economic freedom with political repression. The economic freedom is circumscribed by a major role for the State, with its close relationship with industrial enterprises and the banking system. In its economic lineaments it is a variant of the corporatist model pioneered by Bismarck in Germany in 1871, and adopted by the Meiji reformers in Japan with the promotion of the zaibatsu. After the Second World War, despite the attempt by the Allies to institute the alternative Anglo-Saxon form of capitalism, it was resurrected as the �social market� in Germany and in Japan with the keiretsu replacing the zaibatsu. This corporatism was exported to other Asian countries, most notably South Korea in the 1960s, with the rise of the chaebol.
But, despite being in bed with their favoured industrialists and bankers, the governments of the corporatist form of capitalism, nevertheless, saw themselves politically as very much part of the West. The unique feature of authoritarian capitalism is that the State openly seeks to use this corporatist form of capitalism for political purposes, namely to perpetuate authoritarian rule by commissars who until recently were in the business of burying the capitalist West. Despite their claims to have changed their spots, there must be the continuing worry that these States will use their growing economic power to subvert Western polities.
Similarly, the other source of worry concerns the role of sovereign wealth funds and State-controlled firms in the oil rich autocracies of West Asia (and anti-Western states like Venezuela). These are also countries in the grip of a variant of authoritarian capitalism. Once again the worry is not purely economic, concerning the most efficient deployment of their recently acquired wealth in the world economy, but that it could be used for anti-Western political ends, like the promotion of a worldwide Islamic jihad against infidels and the extinguishing of Israel.
Once the political aspects of the deployment of sovereign wealth by the countries of authoritarian capitalism are openly recognised, many of the calls for the international financial institutions (whose charters prohibit political discrimination) to lay down a code of good behaviour by sovereign wealth agencies seem to be misguided. A code must lay down some general and universally applicable principles. But it is difficult to see how these can be derived when the unstated purpose is to discriminate against some countries that are actual or potential political enemies. Thus consider some of the possible elements of a code.
The most draconian would be to ban all State-controlled entities from investing in Western capital markets or taking over their firms. Though it would have the advantage � at least for classical liberals � that it might force the privatisation of nationalised industries around the world, it would not necessarily lead the States of authoritarian capitalism to cease indirectly directing their seemingly �private� firms to fulfil their political objectives. Whilst at the same time it would make no sense that the State-controlled Norwegian or Alaskan sovereign wealth funds, for instance, could not invest in Western capital markets.
Nor would a ban on sovereign investment in 'strategic' industries make more sense. Apart from defence-related industries where foreign investment is already banned, should sovereign investment in a country's media or sensitive infrastructure like local gas and electricity distribution (which are natural monopolies) be banned? Once again, if the Norwegian or Alaskan sovereign wealth fund decided to buy Murdoch�s News Corp or my London gas distributor, not many sleepless nights would ensue in the West. But if Gazprom were to buy the local gas distribution networks in Europe (as it has envisaged) I would not sleep easily, as it might decide to cut off the supply to my gas stove, in Putin�s ongoing fight with the UK authorities to send his political enemy � the oligarch Boris Berezovsky � back to Moscow. The thought that Gazprom's newly acquired monopoly could be expropriated by the British state would offer me little comfort, as the entrenched rule of law in Britain (unlike in Russia) would prevent this.
Assorted on India
13 years ago
No comments:
Post a Comment